Home » Resources » Return on Assets is Détaché from Economics
Dark Mode
Article, Blog

Return on Assets is Détaché from Economics

website img – 10-2-23_benchmarking_b

The true theorist in economics has to become at the same time a statistician.”

– Ragnar Frisch (1930), p. 30.

Many transfer pricing reports (against Ragnar Frisch’s advice) are devoid of economics or statistics principles. Here, I show that the usual transfer pricing application of “return on assets” (ROA) is disreputable.

The usual ROA application consists of reporting quartiles of the computed ratios (ρ):

(1) P = ρ K,

where the variables P is operating profits and K is operating assets. The unknown parameter ρ = ROA.

The variables P and K are taken after depreciation. Using Standard & Poor’s Compustat mnemonics, I define the variables P = (OIADP + AM) and K = PPENT (property, plant & equipment, net of accumulated depreciation) because these definitions are consistent with accounting and economics principles. In RoyaltyStat, (OIADP + AM) is called OIBAM, i.e., operating profit before the amortization of intangibles.

I disregard the intercept and statistical error in eq. (1) to facilitate exposition.

Two questions are relevant. First, how is the variable K measured? Second, should K be delayed one-period? That is, should K be measured at the beginning or at the period end?

Economics Principles

In economics, K must be measured in cogent terms connecting the balance sheet (where K is reported for tax or book purpose) with the income statement and the cash flow statement of the given enterprise. The consistent terms are provided by the “law of motion” (growth rate) of the aggregate (indecomposable) accounts combining property, plant, and equipment (K):

(2) K − K(−1) = G – δ K(−1), or

(3) K = (1 + γ) K(−1)

Among other references, eq. (2) is found in the specialized economics book by Nickell (1978), eq. 2.5, p. 10 or eq. 7.1, p. 117.

Like P, the depreciation of property, plant, and equipment (i.e., δ K(−1), which is a component of eq. (2)) is reported on the income statement of the selected enterprise, and G (gross investment or CAPX) is reported on the cash flow statement. The parameter δ is the depreciation rate, and γ is the computed growth rate of K. Operating assets in eq. (3) are obtained by dividing eq. (2) by K(−1), and then solving for K.

Substitute eq. (3) into eq. (1) to obtain the reduced-form ROA equation, which can be then subject to empirical testing to determine its statistical significance and explanatory power:

(4) P = ρ (1 + γ) K(−1), or

(5) P = φ K(−1),

where φ = ρ (1 + γ) > 0.

The reduced-form slope coefficient [φ = ROA] in eq. (5) is weighted by the growth rate of K. The one-period lagged variable K(−1) is the appropriate base of ROA, and not K reported at the end of the period.

Statistical Application

Empirical analysis involves an accept or reject decision between two or more competing models, such as eq. (1) versus eq. (5). See Lakatos (1970, p. 118). In economics, model (1) should not be used because it disregards eq. (2). Model (5) is well-specified and can be used for statistical decision-making.

Exhibit 1 shows the least-squares results of profit model (1). Exhibit 2 shows the results of profit model (5). Exhibit 3 compares the slope coefficients ρ versus φ, and they differ because γ is not zero. The statistical significance of the slope coefficients (verify the t-Statistics) of model (1) or (5) is weak, and the explanatory power of each model, measured by the regressions R2, is poor.

This statistical illustration suggests that “return on assets” is not reliable, and other profit indicators such as “return on sales” (ROS can be estimated by indirect least squares) may be more reliable. See my other blog: “Profit Margin by Indirect Least Squares.”

The usual ROA analysis in transfer pricing assumes that γ = 0. As illustrated on the chart below, this special assumption (γ = 0) is unsupported by accounting data from “big oil” conglomerates. The hidden assumption γ = 0, implying that K = K(−1), which is made obvious in eq. (2), is a special case, and must be tested using comparable enterprise data.

This furtive assumption γ = 0 was accepted by the court in Coca-Cola155 T.C. No. 10 Docket No. 31183-15, United States Tax Court. See the court’s uncritical replication of the ROA histogram (“Profitability of Supply Points vs. Global Industry Comparison Group”) in Coca-Cola (p. 112), using eq. (1).

The other IRS misconception applying ROA in Coca-Cola is that its K is an amorphous aggregate, comprising accounts receivable, inventories, and “other” current assets in addition to property, plant and equipment. In origin, the IRS definition of K in Sec. 482-5(d)(6) is incongruous, because it mixes depreciable and non-depreciable assets, and assumes they have the same growth rate and rate of return.

Takeaways

ROA computations in transfer pricing are noisome when they disregard economics or statistics principles. A solution to unacceptable practices is to correct misconceived regulatory guidance, such as the IRS inept definition of “operating assets,” and to force the application of profit indicators that comply with acceptable economics or statistical principles.

References

Olav Bjerkholt & Duo Qin (editors), A Dynamic Approach to Economic Theory (Lectures by Ragnar Frisch at Yale University), Routledge, 2011.

Imre Lakatos & Alan Musgrave (editors), Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge, Cambridge University Press, 1970.

Stephen Nickell, The Investment Decisions of Firms, Cambridge University Press, 1978.

Exhibit 1: Slope Coefficient of Eq. (1)

GVKEY Company Name Count Slope Coef. (%) NW Std Err. (%) t-Stat R2 Intercept at 5%
2410 BP PLC 72 12.05 4.4 2.7388 0.3778 Significant
2991 Chevron Corp 72 8.31 4.72 1.7592 0.2352 Significant
8549 Conocophillips 72 17.08 4.02 4.2483 0.5922 Insignificant
61616 Eni SpA 33 17.87 5.79 3.0873 0.324 Insignificant
4503 Exxon Mobil Corp 72 10.23 4.83 2.1174 0.2514 Significant
7017 Marathon Oil Corp 65 10.93 4.43 2.466 0.3008 Insiginifacnt
12384 Shell Plc 40 4.43 3.66 1.2093 0.0475 Significant
24625 TotalEnergies SE 33 15.78 6.4 2.4681 0.2917 Insignificant
15247 Valero Energy Corp 43 14.44 3.33 4.3376 0.5228 Insignificant
All 502 11.97 2.37 5.0447 0.3549 Significant


Exhibit 2: Slope Coefficient of Eq. (5)

GVKEY Company Name Count Slope Coef. (%) NW Std Err. (%) t-Stat R2 Intercept at 5%
2410 BP PLC 71 11.31 4.83 2.344 0.3249 Significant
2991 Chevron Corp 71 7.31 4.74 1.5428 0.1735 Significant
8549 Conocophillips 71 15.79 4.77 3.3111 0.4912 Insignificant
61616 Eni SpA 32 12.99 6.83 1.9007 0.1739 Insignificant
4503 Exxon Mobil Corp 71 9.46 5.2 1.821 0.2063 Significant
7017 Marathon Oil Corp 64 9.02 4.79 1,8815 0.2047 Insignificant
12384 Shell Plc 39 3.42 3.78 0.9029 0.027 Significant
24625 TotalEnergies SE 32 14.05 6.89 2.0378 0.2276 Insignificant
15247 Valero Energy Corp 42 14.01 3.26 4.301 0.4631 Insignificant


Exhibit 3: ROA with Lagged vs. Not-Lagged K

Big Oil ROA (1)-2